Preview Extract
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
CHAPTER 2
ECONOMISTSโ VIEW OF BEHAVIOR
CHAPTER SUMMARY
This chapter uses the cheating scandal at Merrill Lynch to illustrate how a managerโs
view of behavior can affect decision making. It summarizes the economic view of
behavior and contrasts it with other views. The chapter presents a graphical analysis of
utility maximization and decision making under uncertainty. The concepts in this chapter
are an important foundation for subsequent material in the book.
CHAPTER OUTLINE
ECONOMIC BEHAVIOR: AN OVERVIEW
Economic Choice
Marginal Analysis
Managerial Application: Marginal Analysis of Customer Profitability
Opportunity Costs
Managerial Application: Opportunity Costs and V-8
Creativity of Individuals
Managerial Application: Creative Gaming of the System
GRAPHIC TOOLS
Individual Objectives
Indifference Curves
Constraints
Individual Choice
Changes in Choice
MOTIVATING HONESTY AT MERRILL LYNCH
MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS
Managerial Application: Medicare Creates Perverse Incentives for Doctors
ALTERNATIVE MODELS OF BEHAVIOR
Only-Money-Matters Model
Happy-Is-Productive Model
Managerial Application: Happy-Is-Productive versus Economic
Explanations of the Hawthorne Experiments
Good-Citizen Model
Managerial Application: Culture and Behavior
Product-of-the-Environment Model
WHICH MODEL SHOULD MANAGERS USE?
Academic Application: The Economic Framework and Criminal Behavior
Academic Application: Criticisms of the Happy-Is-Productive Model
2-1
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
DECISION MAKING UNDER UNCERTAINTY
Expected Value
Variability
Risk Aversion
Certainty Equivalent and Risk Premium
Risk Aversion and Compensation
SUMMARY
APPENDIX: CONSUMER CHOICE
Marginal Utility
Slope of an Indifference Curve
Individual Choice
Solving for the Optimal Consumption Bundle
Demand Functions
Income and Substitution Effects
Magnitude of the Substitution Effect
Additional Considerations
Calculus Derivation of the Equal Marginal Principle
TEACHING THE CHAPTER
This chapter begins to focus on the economic tools that are used throughout the rest of the
text. Depending upon the background of the students who are in the class and the
importance of the topic to the overalls goals of the course, instructors will need to spend
varying amounts of time on this chapter and will opt to cover the appendix in varying
levels of detail. The utility-maximization framework is presented graphically and
numerically, with a detailed presentation included in the appendix. Undoubtedly, this
concept is the most difficult part of the chapter but this economic model is vital to
understand. It is imperative that students not only understand how the tools are used for
quantitative and graphical analysis, but also why these tools represent the concepts they
are used to portray (such as opportunity cost). The remaining concepts of the chapter are
not technical in nature so instructors can make use of the Managerial Applications to
generate class discussion of these topics rather than lecturing on them. Alternative views
of behavior are presented and their resulting managerial implications can be used for
class discussion. The last section of the chapter focuses on how decisions are made when
individuals face uncertainty.
The Self-Evaluation Problems cover some of the quantitative tools introduced in the
chapter, including consumer choice analysis, but there are numerous Review Questions
that also cover the quantitative analysis and key concepts. It would be worthwhile to
devote time in class to these questions since this chapter is the foundation for many of the
chapters that follow.
2-2
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
There are five Analyzing Managerial Decisions Scenarios presented in the chapter. The
first scenario, โMarginal Analysisโ, is based on determining the relevant costs that should
be considered when making decisions. The second scenario, โConsumer Choice and
Graphical Toolsโ, asks students to graph indifference curves and budget constraints to
explain the scenario. This scenario relies on graphical analysis of the problem, not a
quantitative analysis. It also highlights the relationship between the economic model and
what it represents. The third scenario, โInterwest Healthcare Corp.โ asks students to
consider the motivations for the workers who are not properly completing their tasks and
how this behavior might be changed. The fourth scenario, โRisk Aversion versus Risk
Taskingโ, focuses on differences in behavior due to individualsโ varying levels of risk
tolerance. This concept is important since it resurfaces in several chapters throughout the
text. The final scenario, โConsumer Choiceโ, is located at the end of the chapter after the
appendix. This scenario focuses on the quantitative analysis of consumer choice.
Instructors should review this scenario and determine its relevancy to the course since it
involves more complicated mathematical analysis than will be used in the rest of the text.
However, instructors whose students have the appropriate mathematical background will
likely want to review this scenario. (See the Solutions Manual for the answers to these
problems).
APPENDIX PROBLEMS
1.
Define the following terms: marginal utility, ordinal utility, marginal rate of
substitution, equal marginal principle, demand function, substitution effect,
income effect, normal good, inferior good, perfect complement, and perfect
substitute.
Marginal utility measures the additional utility that is obtained by consuming
one additional unit of a good, while holding all other goods constant.
Ordinal utility yields the ranking of consumption bundles. Absolute
comparisons based on the levels of utility canโt be made.
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) is the absolute value of the slope of an
indifference curve.
Equal marginal principle (as used in this appendix) is the condition that the
marginal utility per dollar is the same for all goods at the optimum.
Demand function expresses the mathematical relation between the quantity
demanded for a product (how many units consumers will purchase) and the
factors that determine consumer choice (such as prices and income).
Substitution effect is the change in the quantity demanded of a good when its
price changes, holding the prices of other goods and utility constant.
2-3
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
Income effect is the change in the quantity demanded of a good because of a
change in income, holding prices constant.
Normal good is a good whose demand increases (decreases) with increases
(decreases) in income.
Inferior good is a good whose demand decreases (increases) with increases
(decreases) in income.
Perfect complements have indifference curves shaped as right angles. In this
case, the two goods are used in fixed proportions.
Perfect substitutes have indifference curve that are shaped as straight lines. In
this case the consumer purchases only one of the two goods (unless the slopes
of the budget line and indifference curve are the same).
2.
Susan Pettitโs preferences for coffee (by the pound) and doughnuts (by the
dozen), can be characterized as follows:
MUcoffee = MUx = y2
MUdoughnuts = MUy = 2xy
a.
If the ratio of relative prices is (Px/Py) = 6/3 = 2, and Susanโs income is
$90 per period, what combination of pounds of coffee and dozens of
doughnuts will she choose?
At Susanโs optimum:
y2/2xy = 2
y = 4x (1)
Given Susanโs income:
6x + 3 (4x) = 90 Coffee: X = 5 Doughnuts: Y = 20 (from
equation 1)
b.
Now let the ratio of coffee to doughnut prices decline to unity (=1),
holding the price of doughnuts constant. How does Susan respond to the
reduction in the relative price of coffee?
y2/2xy = 1 y = 2x
2-4
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
3x + 3 (2x) = 90 Coffee: X = 10 Doughnuts: Y = 20
Thus, the decline in the price of coffee motivates Susan to increase her
consumption of coffee to 10 units (she continues to consume 20
doughnuts)
c.
Redo parts (a) and (b) for the case of income of $60 per period
Redoing part a:
6x + 3 (4x) = 60 Coffee: X = 3.33 Doughnuts: 13.32 units
Redoing part b:
3x + 3 (2x) = 60 Coffee: X = 6.66 Doughnuts: Y = 13.32 units
d.
Derive Susanโs demand function for coffee.
y/2x = px/py y = (2x)px (1)
From the budget line: x = (I-pyy)/px (2)
Substituting equation (2) into equation (1)and solving for y:
Y = 2/3 (I/py)
e.
Is coffee a normal or inferior good for this consumer?
Coffee is a normal good for Susan since its consumption increases
with income.
f.
Does Susan consider coffee and doughnuts to be either perfect
complements or perfect substitutes? Explain.
No they are neither perfect substitutes are complements. Susan does
not consume the two goods in fixed proportions (so they are not
complements). She also does consume only one good as relative prices
change (so they are not perfect substitutes). The marginal rate of
substitution (y/2x) continuously declines as Susan consumes more x
and less y along an indifference curve.
3.
Susanโs demand function for coffee in the previous problem includes only the
price of coffee and income. Thus changes in the price of doughnuts do not affect
the demand for coffee. Does this imply that there is no substitution effect between
the two goods? Explain.
2-5
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
No. The fact that the price of coffee is not in Susanโs demand curve for
doughnuts does not imply that there is no substitution effect between the two
products. With convex indifference curves there is always a positive
substitution effect. The demand curve reflects both the income and
substitution effects. Increasing (decreasing) the price of coffee motivates
Susan to substitute toward (away from) doughnuts. However, this change in
her demand for doughnuts is exactly offset by the income effect from the
change in her effective income as the price of coffee changes.
4.
Mario Casali is a TV newscaster who gets an annual clothing allowance to buy
suits that he must wear during his televised forecasts. He allocates the allowance
each year between expensive Italian suits and cheap American suits. Marioโs
utility function for suits is IA.5 where I is the number of Italian suits bought and A
is the number of American suits bought. Last year, Mario bought two Italian suits
and four American suits. [Note: MUI = A.5 and MUA = .5IA(-.5)]
a.
If Mario was maximizing his utility last year, what was the ratio of the
price of an Italian suit to the price of an American suit (PI/PA)?
At Marioโs optimal choice:
MUI/MUA = PI/PA
A.5/.5A(-.5)I = PI/PA
A/.5I = PI/PA
4/.5(2) = 4 = PI/PA
b.
What was Marioโs clothing allowance last year if the price of an Italian
suit was $1,000?
PI = $1000 implies that PA = $250 (from part a)
Clothing allowance = $1000 ร 2 + $250 ร 4 = $3000
2-6
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
c.
If Mario has the same allowance this year as last year, and American suit
prices have not changed, how high would the price of Italian suits have to
rise in order for Mario to want to buy exactly one Italian suit this year?
As given in the problem, let I = 1
From the budget line:
$250 ร A + PI ร 1 = $3,000
A = 12 โ (PI/250)
From the optimal condition stated in part a: (12 โ (PI/250)/.5 = PI/250
PI = $2000
(Alternatively, the optimal condition in part a implies that PAA =
.5IPI; this implies that Mario will always spend 1/3rd of his budget on
A and 2/3rd if budget on I; thus P = $2000 when the I = 1 and the
clothing allowance is $3,000)
REVIEW QUESTIONS
2โ1.
Which costs are pertinent to economic decision making? Which costs are not
relevant?
The marginal (incremental) costs and benefits are pertinent to economic
decision making. Sunk costs and benefits are not relevant. In economics,
โbygones are forever bygones.โ
2-7
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
2-2. A noted economist was asked what he did with his โfree time.โ He
responded by saying that โtime is not free.โ Explain this response.
Time is finite. If it is used for one activity it cannot be used for another
activity. Thus using time for one activity involves an opportunity cost (the
value of using the time for the best alternative use). For example, if you
spend an hour of time managing your own business when you could have
used the hour to earn $20 working for someone else, the opportunity cost of
working in your own business is $20/hour.
2-3.
The Solace Company has an inventory of steel that it originally purchased for
$20,000. It currently has an offer to sell the steel for $30,000. Should Solaceโs
management agree to sell? Explain.
You cannot answer this question without additional information. The
historic cost of the steel is irrelevant. What is important is the current
opportunity cost of the steel. For example, if the current market price of steel
is $40,000 you should not sell the steel for $30,000.
2-4.
Suppose that you have $900 and what to invest the money for one year. There are three
existing options.
(a) The city of Rochester is selling bonds at $90 per unit. The bonds pay $100 at the end
of one year when they mature (no other cash flows).
(b) Put the money under your mattress.
(c) The one-year interest rate of saving in the Chase Bank is 7 percent.
Which one will you choose? What is the opportunity cost of your choice? Explain.
Choose option (a). By definition, opportunity cost is the value of the best
foregone option. So the opportunity cost of (a) is the value of (c) in this case,
$63 = $900 ร7%.
2-5.
Suppose Juanโs utility function is given by U = FC, where F and C are the two
goods available for purchase: food and clothing.
a. Graph Juanโs indifference curves for the following levels of utility: 100, 200,
and 300.
2-8
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
Juanโs indifference curves for U = 100, 200 and 300 are pictured as
follows. The general formula for the graph of an indifference curve for
a given level of utility, U*, is F=U*/C (since U* = F x C). For example,
the indifference curve for U* = 100 is given by the formula: F = 100/C.
b. Are these curves convex or concave to the origin? What does this shape imply
about Juanโs willingness to trade food for clothing?
The curves are convex to the origin. This implies that Juanโs
willingness to trade food for clothing falls when the amount of food
that he has declines relative to the amount of clothing. He is willing to
give up a relatively large amount of food for a unit of clothing when he
has lots of food and little clothing. This is not true when he has little
food and numerous clothing.
c. Suppose Juanโs budget is $100 and the prices of F and C are both $5.
the budget constraint.
2-9
Graph
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
Juanโs budget constraint (I = $100 and PC = PF = $5) is pictured as
follows:
d. How many units of food and clothing will Juan purchase at these prices and
income? Show graphically. What is his corresponding level of utility?
Juan will purchase 10 units of food and 10 units of clothing. This
provides Juan with 100 units of utility. Note that at current prices he
can buy a total of 20 units of the two goods (in any combination). Any
other combination produces lower utility. For example, 9 units of one
good and 11 units of the other produces 99 units of utility.
Graphically:
2-10
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
e. The Johnson Company is the sole producer of clothing. What can the company
do to induce Juan to purchase more clothing? Show graphically. (The graph does
not have to be exact.)
It can lower the price of clothing. Graphically (does not have to be
exact)
2-6.
Suppose that Bobโs indifference curves are straight lines (as opposed to being
convex to the origin). What does this imply about Bobโs willingness to trade one
good for the other? Give examples of goods where this type of behavior might be
expected?
Straight line indifference curves indicate that Bobโs willingness to trade one
good for the other does not depend on the amount of each good he currently
owns. This is the case of perfect substitutes. Consider the example of $5 bills
and $10 bills. Your willingness to trade $5 bills for $10 bills is likely to
remain at two for one, independent of how many bills of each kind you have.
For example, if you have no $10 bills and a bunch of $5 bills you are still
unlikely to trade more than two $5 bills to obtain a $10 bill. Another example
is two brands of orange juice that you like equally as well.
2-7.
Suppose that Bobโs indifference curves are perfectly L-shaped with the right angle
occurring when Bob has equal amounts of both goods. What does this imply about
Bobโs willingness to trade one good for the other? Give examples of goods where
this type of behavior might be expected?
2-11
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
Perfectly L-shaped indifference curves imply that the Bob considers the two
goods to be perfect complements. His utility does not increase if receives
more of one of the goods without receiving more of the other good. One
potential example is left and right shoes. Obtaining additional left shoes
without obtaining matching right shoes is unlikely to increase a personโs
utility very much (assuming the person has two feet).
2โ8. a. Briefly describe the five models of behavior presented in this chapter.
Economic Model: People are creative maximizers of their own personal
happiness (utility). Happiness can depend on many factors, including wealth,
integrity, community respect, and so on.
Only-Money-Matters Model: All people care about is money. People act to
maximize their monetary income. Same as economic model except that
people care only about money.
Happy-is-Productive Model: Happy employees are more productive than
unhappy employees.
Good-Citizen Model: Employees want to do a good job. Managers simply
need to communicate the goals and objectives of the organization to the
employees.
Product-of-the-Environment Model: The behaviors of individuals are largely
determined by their upbringings.
b. What are the implications of these models for managers attempting to
influence their employees’ behavior?
The economic model suggests that managers should focus on incentives
(monetary or otherwise) in trying to motivate behavior. The only-moneymatters model suggests that managers should use only monetary incentives in
trying to motivate behavior. The happy-is productive model suggests that
productivity can be increased by enriching jobs and engaging in other
activities to increase employee happiness. The good-citizen model suggests
that managers should focus on communicating firm goals to employees. The
product-of-the environment model suggests that managers should focus on
hiring employees with a strong work ethic.
2-12
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
2โ9.
Employees in a plant in Minnesota are observed to be industrious and very
productive. Employees in a similar plant in Southern California are observed to be
lazy and unproductive. Discuss how alternative views of human behavior and
motivation might suggest different explanations for this observed behavior.
The economic model suggests the employees in the two locations have
different compensation or incentive schemes. Incentives to be productive
appear to be higher at the Minnesota plant. Or, if the compensation plans are
the same, the alternative employment opportunities differ so that individuals
with different talents are attracted to the two plants. The only money-matters
model is similar to the economic model in its explanation. However, the focus
is exclusively on monetary incentives. The happy-is productive model
suggests that employees are happier at the Minnesota plant. The good-citizen
model suggests that employees at the Southern California plant do not realize
that it is important to the firm for them to work hard. The product-of-theenvironment model suggests that the employees at the two plants are from
different backgrounds. The employees at the Minnesota plant have a
stronger work ethic.
2โ10. Employees at a department store are observed engaging in the following behavior:
(a) they hide items that are on sale from the customers, and (b) they exert little
effort in designing merchandise displays. They are also uncooperative with one
another. What do you think might be causing this behavior, and what might you
do to improve the situation?
The employees apparently are paid in a way that motivates this behavior. For
instance, they might be paid a large sales commission on their personal sales.
This commission plan might motivate employees to hide items on sale so that
they can convince customers to buy higher-priced items. The commission
scheme also might provide limited incentives to engage in nonselling
activities, such as designing merchandise displays or helping coworkers. It is
also likely that employees do not expect to work for the store for a long time
period (turnover is high). Otherwise, they would have an incentive to build
longer-term relationships with customers (to increase future sales
commissions) and co-workers. The situation might be improved by changing
the compensation scheme to increase the incentives to engage in nonselling
activities and to consider the long-term implications of an action (such as
creating customer expectations that the store will be out of items that are on
sale).
2-13
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
2โ11. One of the main tenets of economic analysis is that people act in their own self
interest. Why then do people leave tips in restaurants? If a study were to compare
the size of tips earned by servers in restaurants on interstate highways with those
in restaurants near residential neighborhoods, what would you expect to find?
Why?
When a customer comes into a restaurant in the U.S. they have an implicit
contract with the waiter to tip for good service. A customer might honor this
contract for two reasons. First, the person might value being fair and not
want to shirk on the implicit agreement (economics allows for people to care
about fairness). Second, the customer will realize that if he shirks on the tip
the next time he comes back to the restaurant the waiter will shirk on service.
Tips are likely to be higher at restaurants in residential neighborhoods
because the second effect (the repeat-customer effect) is likely to be large.
Restaurants on interstate highways will be frequented by many customers
who will not return. These customers have large incentives to shirk on the tip
unless they care significantly about fairness to the waiter.
2โ12. Several school districts have attempted to increase teacher productivity by paying
teachers based on the scores their students achieve on standardized tests
(administered by outside testing agencies). The goal is to produce higher quality
classroom instruction. Do you think that this type of compensation scheme will
produce the desired outcome? Explain.
Compensation plans of this type provide incentives for teachers to emphasize
the material covered in the texts. Yet such plans sometimes produce bad side
effects. Teachers will have strong incentives to focus on test scores. This focus
does not necessarily produce better teaching. In part, it depends on how well
the tests measure learning. Moreover, some teachers are likely to discover
ways to โgame the compensation scheme.โ For instance, in some school
districts, this type of compensation scheme has motivated teachers to teach
the material to be tested rather than provide a more general education. In
extreme cases, teachers get advanced copies of the exam and give the answers
to students before the test.
2โ13. A company recently raised the pay of employees by 20 percent. Employee
productivity remained the same. The CEO of the company was quoted as saying,
“it just goes to show that money does not motivate people.” Provide a critical
evaluation of this statement.
2-14
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
According to the economic model simply raising pay by 20 percent is unlikely
to increase productivity. The employees may be happier but not more
productive. What is important is tying the pay raise to productivity. In this
case, employees would be expected to exert more effort to increase the
likelihood of the pay raise.
2โ14. One physician who worked for a large health maintenance organization was
quoted as saying:
One day I was listening to a patient’s heart and realized there was
an abnormal rhythm. My first thought was that I hoped that I did
not have to refer the patient to a specialist.
Indeed, HMO physicians have been criticized for not making referrals when they
are warranted. How do you think the physician was compensated by the HMO?
Explain.
The physician was obviously concerned about treatment expenses.
Presumably, the HMO was paying the physician based on the total treatment
costs for the patient. For example, the HMO might be paying the physician a
fixed fee for treating each patient minus some function of any treatment costs
(for example, payments to other specialists, and so on).
2โ15. Insurance companies have to generate enough revenue to cover their costs and
make a normal profit โ otherwise, they will go out of business. This implies that
the premiums charged for insurance policies must be greater than the expected
payouts to the policyholders. Why would a person ever buy insurance, knowing
that the price is greater than the expected payout?
Risk-averse people are willing to pay a premium for insurance. They prefer a
certain outcome to a less certain outcome and are willing to give up some
expected value in order to reduce risk.
2โ16. Critically evaluate the following statement: โRisk-averse people never take
gambles.โ
2-15
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
Risk-averse people do take gambles. The expected return, however, has to be
sufficiently high to offset the increased risk the person accepts. Note: There is
frequently a difference between attitudes toward risk with respect to an
individualโs investment portfolio as opposed to placing a bet on a sports contest.
We believe that this distinction can be used to motivate a discussion of the
multifaceted nature of consumption. If placing a bet on the Super Bowl or
world cup makes watching the game more interesting, then only part of the
benefit of the bet comes from the expected cash payoff โ the other part is the
enhanced enjoyment of the game.
2โ17. Suppose that an investment can yield three possible cash flows: $5,000; $1,000; or
$0. The probability of each outcome is 1/3.
a. What is the expected value and standard deviation of the investment?
expected value = $2,000; standard deviation = $1,825
b. How much would a risk-neutral person be willing to pay for the investment?
$2,000 (ignoring the time-value of money)
c. How much would a risk-averse person be willing to pay for the
investment?
Something less than $2,000 (the exact amount depends on the level of
risk aversion).
2โ18. In order to spur consumer spending in 1998, the Japanese government considered
an $85 billion voucher system whereby every Japanese consumer would receive a
shopping voucher that could be used to purchase Japanese products. For
simplicity, assume the following: each consumer has wealth of 1 million yen,
consumers must allocate this wealth between consumption now (c1), and
consumption later (c2), the interest rate is zero, the voucher is worth 100,000 yen,
and it can be spent only in the current period. If it is not spent, it is lost.
a. Plot a budget line for a representative consumer both before and after the
voucher program (c1 and c2 are on the axes).
2-16
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
b. Do you expect that current consumption of a typical consumer will increase by
the full 100,000 yen of the voucher? Explain.
While in principle it could โ it depends on the tangency points
between the indifference curves and the budget lines โ most likely
consumption in the current period will not increase by the full
100,000. Rather, some will be saved for the future.
c. How does the impact of this 100,000-yen voucher differ from simply giving the
individual 100,000 yen?
It will have the same effect unless the average consumer wants to save
more than 1,000,000 for the future (out of a 1,100,000 budget). The
budget line with a pure cash supplement would be the same as
pictured above except that it would fully extend to the y-axis. As long
as the tangency point between the indifference curve and budget line
occurs at a point where future consumption is below 1,000,000, there
will be no difference. If the tangency occurs in the extended region,
the consumer will save the maximum possible (1,000,000 and spend
100,000 in the current period โ a corner solution).
2โ19. People give to charity.
a. Is this action consistent with the โeconomic view of behaviorโ? Explain.
There is nothing in the Economic View that says that people canโt
gain utility from contributing to good causes. Also they may be doing
this to create good will in the community. This might result in more
business opportunities, less government red tape in completing
transactions, etc.
2-17
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
b. Suppose that there is a big drop in charitable giving. At the same time there has
been no decline in per capita income or total employment. Using the economic
model, what potential factors might have led to this decline in giving?
Economic analysis focuses on how changes in constraints (rather than
preferences) effect behavior. One potential variable that might have
changed is the tax code. For instance, deductions may have been
eliminated making it more expensive to give to charity. The economic
view would not typically make arguments like โpeopleโs preferences
changed and thus they no longer felt like giving to charity.โ
c. How might the decline in giving be explained by the product-of-the
environment model?
The product-of-the-environment model argues that peopleโs behavior
is explained by their upbringing and social background. Under this
view, some people who were brought up to care about others give to
charity, while others do not. Perhaps while per capita income has not
changed, there has been a shift in income away from the giving group
to the nongiving group, making giving less likely. Also, there may
have been demographic changes due to relocations, deaths, etc.
2-20. The Japanese are very good at returning lost property to local police stations. If
you lose a wallet filled with cash in Japan it is likely to be turned into the police.
This is true even though the person finding it could keep it without anyone else
knowing. This behavior is not what you would find in New York City.
a. Does this observation about Japan imply that the economic model does not
explain behavior in Japan? Explain.
The economic model of behavior asserts that individuals are
interested in maximizing their own utility. In making decisions,
individuals consider the incremental costs and benefits and make
decisions only when the incremental benefits are larger than the costs.
Decisions can change with changes in the incremental costs or
benefits.
Turning in wallets full of cash is not inconsistent with the economic
model. The marginal disutility from being dishonest might be larger
than the benefits of the extra money given the typical Japanese utility
function (given the typical amount of money found in the wallets).
There is nothing in the economic model to say that people only care
about money.
2-18
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
b. Police stations in Japan are filled with lost umbrellas. It used to be that the
typical Japanese would make a trip to the local police station to search for a lost
umbrella. Now they donโt. Explain this behavior using the Economic Model.
The economic model predicts that peopleโs behavior can change with
changes in incremental costs or benefits. In the case of going to search
for an umbrella there are a number of possibilities. First with
increases in income of the typical Japanese worker, the opportunity
cost of taking time to search for an umbrella has increased. This
increase in marginal costs makes the choice less likely. Another
possibility is that the price of replacing an umbrella has decreased so
that the marginal benefit of finding an umbrella is smaller.
c. Do you think that the typical Japanese is more likely to come to a police station
to find a lost cell phone or a lost umbrella? Explain using the Economic Model.
The marginal costs of going to the police station are likely to be the
same in either case. However, the price and nonpecuniary costs of
replacing a lost cell phone are likely to be higher than for an
umbrella. Since the marginal benefits are more likely to exceed the
marginal costs for retrieving cell phones, the economic model predicts
that people are more likely to search for cell phones.
2โ21. Some states in the U.S. allow citizens to carry handguns. Citizens can protect
themselves in the case of robberies by using these guns. Other states do not allow
citizens to carry handguns. Criminals, however, tend to have handguns in all
states. Use economic analysis to predict the effects of handgun laws on the
behavior of the typical criminal. In particular: (1) Do you think criminals will
commit more or fewer robberies in the states with the laws? (2) How do you think
the laws will affect the types of robberies criminals commit? Be sure to explain
your economic reasoning.
Based on the economic model, criminals are expected to consider the
marginal costs and benefits of their actions in choosing the level and type of
crime. Allowing citizens to carry handguns increases the marginal costs of
robberies, since the criminals are more likely to get hurt or killed. Thus the
economic model predicts that there will be fewer robberies in the states
where handguns are allowed.
The laws affect the marginal costs of some types of crimes more than others.
Crimes involving personal contact are the ones most likely to be affected by
the laws. Therefore, the economic model suggests that criminals will
substitute away from crimes involving personal contact to crimes of stealth
in states where handguns are allowed.
2-19
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
Note: a study was conducted on this topic and both predictions were supported
by the data.
2โ22. Discuss the following statement: โSunk costs matter. People who pay $20,000 to
join a golf club play golf more frequently than people who play on public golf
courses.โ
People who pay $20,000 to join a golf club are likely to have a greater than
average interest in playing golf. They may still consider only the marginal
costs (e.g., time) and benefits in choosing how much to play. However, given
their interest in golf (marginal benefits are high) they will tend to play
frequently. Thus, the observation is more likely to reflect โself selectionโ
than sunk costs.
2-23. Jenny is an investor in the stock market. She cares about both the expected value
and standard deviation of her investment. Currently she is invested in a security
that has an expected value of $15,000 and a standard deviation of $5,000. This
places her on an indifference curve with the following formula: Expected Value =
$10,000 + Standard Deviation.
a. Is Jenny risk averse? Explain.
Yes, Jenny is risk averse. She is willing to take on more risk only if it
is associated with a sufficiently higher expected return.
b. What is Jennyโs โcertainty equivalentโ for her current investment? What does
this mean?
The certainty equivalent is $10,000. She would be willing to accept a
certain return of $10,000 (the vertical intercept of her indifference
curve) in lieu of her current risky investment which has an expected
return of $15,000 and a standard deviation of $5,000.
c. What is the risk premium on her current investment?
The risk premium on her current investment is $5,000. This is the
difference in the expected return of her risky investment and the riskfree investment. The $5,000 risk premium is what it takes in expected
return to make her indifferent between the risk and risk free
investments.
2-20
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
2-24. Accounting problems at Enron ultimately led to the collapse of the large
accounting firm Arthur Andersen. When the Enron scandal first became public,
Andersenโs top management blamed one โrouge partnerโ in the Houston office
who they claimed was less honest than other partners at the firm. They fired the
partner and asked that people not hold the remaining partners accountable for
โone bad apple.โ What model of behavior was Andersenโs management using
when it analyzed the source of the problem? According to the economic view of
behavior, what was the more likely cause of the problem?
Andersenโs statement is most consistent with the product-of-the environment
model. According to this view, there was a โrogue partnerโ who was not
raised with the same moral and ethical values as most of the other partners.
In this case, Andersenโs future problems would be solved by firing the bad
apple and hiring a replacement with higher ethical values. The economic
view of behavior would suggest that partners were acting in their own self
interest given the costs and benefits that they faced. The capstone case at the
end of Part 3 of the book provides a detailed study of Arthur Andersen. The
evidence in this case suggests that the partners were motivated to be overly
lenient on audits because of Andersenโs performance evaluation system
which encouraged them strongly to obtain additional business from their
audit customers. One potential way to attract additional business from
companies is to be easy on them in annual audits.
2-25. According to a recent article in The Atlanta Journal-Constitution (Jan., 29th 2004),
โmaterialism, not necessity, gave birth to dual-income families.โ In supporting the
argument, the author cites the following figures from the Department of
Commerce: in 1970 the average wage per job was $6,900, which in 2001 dollars
(adjusting for inflation) amounts to $31,500. In 2001, the average wage per job
was $35,500. The main thesis of the article is that dual-income families are a
result of a shift in consumer preferences toward consumption as opposed to
leisure time/time spent with the family.
(a)
Assume the average person worked 250 days during a year both in 1970
and 2001, and that, as reported in the article, only one person worked in
the average family in 1970, while both parents did in 2001. Provide a
graphical analysis of the typical familyโs choice between family income
and combined parent leisure time that supports the authorโs argument,
relying on the tools presented in class. Be careful in labeling your
graph(s), and provide a clear and concise explanation for your graph(s).
Note that there are 365 days in a year so that the total parent leisure time
that is possible is 730 days (assuming neither spouse works). Assume it is
possible for each family member to work anywhere from 0 to 365 days a
year (at the going salary rate) if they choose to do so.
2-21
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
In the figure above, the curves corresponding to the average 1970 family are
given by the dashed lines, while the curves corresponding to the average 2001
family are given by the full lines.
In particular, if both parents worked 365 days per year (i.e. 0 days of leisure
combined), the family would earn $91,980 in 1970, while in 2001 the same
family would earn $103,660, given the figures in the article, and assuming
average daily income did not vary with the number of days worked. If
neither parent worked any day of the year, the combined number of leisure
days is 730 and the total income is 0 in both years.
The two indifference maps (i.e. sets of indifference curves) drawn for the
typical 1970 and 2001 family are consistent with the authorโs argument that
familiesโ preferences have changed over time. Indeed, since the indifference
curves of the typical 1970 family cross those of the typical 2001 family, they
could not be representing the same set of preferences, as this would violate
one of the 3 basic assumptions underlying well-behaved preferences
(transitivity).
2-22
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
It should be noted that although the authorโs argument is consistent with
consumer optimization behavior, this does not mean that it is the only
plausible explanation. In particular, as reported in the article, the average
daily income has increased from 1970 to 2001 and, thus, the price of leisure
has increased. Therefore, even holding preferences constant over time, it
could be that families choose now to work more because the opportunity cost
of not working has increased. See the next question for further details on this
argument.
(b)
Assume that in 1971 the average single person worked 220 days per year,
while the same person worked 260 days per year in 2001. Moreover,
suppose the average daily wage in 2001 dollars was $125 in 1970 and
$140 in 2001. Show graphically how the authorโs argument would not
necessarily apply to the average single person (i.e. assume preferences are
unchanged). Explain clearly and concisely why the average worker may
be choosing to work more in 2001 and carefully label your graph.
As the figure above shows, it is very well possible that the same person (i.e.
having identical preferences) chooses two different bundles of income and
leisure time after a wage rate change.
2-23
Chapter 02 – Economistsโ View Of Behavior
In particular, an increase in the daily wage produces two distinct effects:
first, the person is able to earn more after the increase, holding constant the
number of leisure days he/she chooses to enjoy, or, similarly, the person
could earn the same total income while enjoying more leisure time. However,
at the same time, an increase in the daily wage rate increases the opportunity
cost of leisure time.
Whether a person will choose to work more or less after the change depends
on which of these two effects dominates, given the personโs preferences. The
indifference map in the graph above represents a set of preferences such that
the second effect (increase in the relative price of leisure โ substitution effect)
dominates the first (the increase in income โ income effect).
The picture and explanation above complement the argument offered in the
previous answer. That is, the higher number of dual-income families in
recent year, which is documented in the article, is not necessarily the result of
changing preferences. On the contrary, it could well be that, given the
average familyโs preferences, higher wages cause families to choose to work
more.
2-24
Document Preview (24 of 336 Pages)
User generated content is uploaded by users for the purposes of learning and should be used following SchloarOn's honor code & terms of service.
You are viewing preview pages of the document. Purchase to get full access instantly.
-37%
Solution Manual for Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
24/7 Live Chat
Instant Download
100% Confidential
Store
Lucas Clark
0 (0 Reviews)
Best Selling
Solution Manual for Designing the User Interface: Strategies for Effective Human-Computer Interaction, 6th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Chemistry: Principles And Reactions, 7th Edition Test Bank
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Test Bank for Hospitality Facilities Management and Design, 4th Edition
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
2023-2024 ATI Pediatrics Proctored Exam with Answers (139 Solved Questions)
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
Data Structures and Other Objects Using C++ 4th Edition Solution Manual
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)
The World Of Customer Service, 3rd Edition Test Bank
$18.99 $29.99Save:$11.00(37%)